Mutual credit clubs: an introduction, with Dil Green

Mutual Credit Services helps establish mutual credit clubs

Dil Green had the original idea for ‘mutual credit clubs’ that can federate to create a new global trading system. He’s brought together a group of people to form Mutual Credit Services (MCS) to start to build this federation (new website coming soon).

Hi Dil – Dil is a member of the Lowimpact co-op, and was introduced to me by Matthew Slater, author of the Credit Commons white paper. You had an idea earlier this year, that’s culminated in my getting the book deal. There’s a lot of specialist knowledge I need to extract, to translate for a bigger audience, and to slot into the book. It’s apt I think to start those interviews with you, because it’s your idea about mutual credit clubs that’s got me to this position.

We’ve been talking about mutual credit on Lowimpact for a while now – the position is that humanity is on a very destructive path, which will be impossible to get off as long as we have this money system.

I’m going to ask you a some questions that I’m typically asked. Not all of them – just the sensible ones. I’d like to make sure the answers make sense to complete beginners. I’ve got quite a few questions, so very briefly if you can.

First – why are you doing this?

It’s the thing that I feel I can do and make some difference in, which seems to have the potential to contribute most deeply to sorting out the trouble we’re in. There are lots of people doing lots of different things, and we need all of them, and I’m not knocking anyone else’s choices – just wish them good luck. But it seems strongly to me that, for reasons of historical accident, the sort of money we use drives extractive behaviour and excessive competitive behaviour and discourages and disincentivises collaborative behaviour, and changing that might do a lot to make a lot of good ideas and things that other people are doing work better.

We worked on the Open Credit Network (OCN) together – a national network for the UK. Why did you switch to the MCS idea?

Essentially, mutual credit works by operationalised trust – it takes trust that exists or can be developed between trading partners and turns it into something real – i.e. more access to credit. The problem with the OCN (and it’s a great thing, and a huge step forward) is because it’s a national network of individual businesses, the ability to generate trust is relatively low. Businesses don’t know each other and aren’t in trading relationships with each other. So with MCS we’re looking to have smaller groups of trading partners, where trust can be strong.

So – mutual credit clubs – groups of businesses that trade together in mutual credit, that can be federated into wider networks that can encompass the globe. Very exciting. And very useful in post-Covid times when there’s not going to be much money about. So people read the book, they think great – How can I join in? When?

The key thing that is hard to understand is that, in the West particularly, individuals are not allowed to create economic value. But we’re only really permitted to create economic value within some business entity. This is a great takeover of human endeavour in capitalism – individuals don’t have the means of production. Things are different in the developing world – they often don’t need any institutional structure. But even people who think they’re individual creatives in wealthy countries, like writers or artists etc. actually have to engage with businesses in order to be able to create economic value out of the human value that they create with their work. To join in, you have to be part of something. So we’re starting with business to business networks, but that’s including social enterprises, charities and sole traders; plus productive community groups – so an allotment association could form a club and trade.

Where are we with the tech? What will the package that local network conveners get look like? when? what’s required to make it happen?

There’s a fair bit of work to be done to have something that works ‘out of the box’, but what we have got is the most complex, innovative aspect of it done – which is the definition and operations of any club – the ledger, i.e. the big book in which all the trades are written down – the digital version of that. Every club is a stand-alone, mutual organisation, owned by its members, runs its own internal accounts system. Each ledger can then federate to another ledger, and the ledgers aren’t strictly linked, they’re just connected by messages about trades. ‘I want to send 100 credits to this business in your group’ – is a typical message. So we’ve got that software up and running, it’s open source (and in a reference implementation), which is great. What then matters for each club is how they send those messages. That’s going to be different in different contexts. We have a very basic banking app front end that we’re using internally, and that can be developed. But we’re essentially in development of various funded contexts where we’ll produce useable interfaces to that ledger software that makes sense for different businesses in different context. The easiest way might be to integrate it into their existing accounting packages. It’s just like another bank account or a Paypal account on their system.

Roughly, any idea when this will be ready for clubs to have, and to get going?

You could start now – we could do it for you if you’re a good enough prospect, and you wouldn’t need any new software at all. That’s what we’ll be doing with the first few projects. It will never be ‘done’ – it will be an evolving process, but I’d say that in 8 months or so, we should be in a much better position.

So when the book comes out, hopefully next autumn, there are going to be some projects to point at?

We’re working hard to make that be the case.

And what if someone watching / reading this wants a club, whether they’re a business network, an accountant, a local authority – anyone who’s interested in having a club – what do they do? Should they just contact MCS through the website?

Yes. At the moment, our capacities aren’t enormous, and we need to focus on key projects we can see have a strong chance of building a working model, because that’s what we need to be able to point at to get funding, whether that’s investment or grants – we need to be able to start showing people how this really works, and we’re making great strides.

It’s relatively easy to explain how people trade in a mutual credit world (I’ve explained it successfully to my friend’s 7-year old son), but how do they save? Probably the most common question I’m asked – in a mutual credit world, how do I buy a house?

We’re never going to have a mutual credit world, in the way we have a hard currency world at the moment. Money is used for every economic purpose. We measure economic tools in hard currency – or at least we think we do. Pensions don’t work like hard currency. Corn futures don’t work like hard currency. But we measure them all in hard currency. We realised that if you use one type of money for measuring everything, and one of the functions of that money is savings – technically called store of value – then there’s a problem with money supply, because people will keep hoarding it, because they need security in old age, or they want to make a large investment, or they want insurance against risk. And those are all very important things that we need in society. But if we use the same money that we use to trade, there will be problems. Money should flow – pass between people as fast as possible to enable value creation and trade. Mutual credit is designed not to be a store of value. So if you want to save, we won’t have a mutual credit world, we’ll have a mutual credit and use credit world – and use credits are different from mutual credit. Use credits are like vouchers for particular services. The key ones are energy, rent, food etc. Those things will be how you save. Because if you’ve got rent credits stored up, you don’t have to worry about having somewhere to live.

This is Chris Cook’s thing, isn’t it? I’m going to interview Chris later on, so I’ll get him to go into more detail on that.

Yes. And it’s worth reading an article called ‘2 Planks and a Bridge’, which explains simply how these 2 mechanisms can work together to cover this.

I’ll blog that article on Lowimpact soon. The second most common question. What if someone defaults / does a runner?

So, we’ll have relatively small groups. The rules will say that you can’t leave a group with a negative account. If you try to do that, you’ll be pursued through the law. But people will default – they’ll go bust, through no fault of their own, and they’ll die. There are 2 things to note. If I’m a business in the current economy and I invoice Dave and give you 30 days to pay – that’s credit. Mutual credit isn’t much different to that, except that the credit is pooled in the group. If I issue credit in the standard way, and he gets run over by a bus, and I’ve already delivered the goods / services, then I’m out of pocket. If Dave and I were part of a mutual credit club, he would have paid me immediately – as soon as the invoice is accepted.

So your account would just get those credits immediately.

Yes, so I would have the credit units. Dave gets run over by a bus…

I’m not liking this story much.

Don’t go out. At least you’re not a crook – you’re just dead. So Dave ceases trading. But it’s not a dead loss. I’ve still got your credit units, and there are still all the other members of the club who accept those credits. So the default doesn’t fall on any individual. We’ve lost as a group. We’ve lost Dave as a trading partner. But we haven’t lost as individuals. Plus, if someone defaults, and if the mutual credit economy is growing, they’ll probably want to join another club. Clubs will ask questions and hear news. It’s likely that they’ll find out why they left the club they used to be in, and refuse them membership. There could be a blacklist they could check.

And the third most common question: I’m not a sole trader and I’m not part of a small business – I work for a large company. Can I still join in? If the company I work for joins, Can they pay their staff in mutual credit?

Sardex in Sardinia is the most exciting and dynamic example of a recently-founded mutual credit network. They’ve introduced in the last 3 years a business-to-employee trading mechanism. Instead of some of their wages, employees get credits to use in the mutual credit network. So the employee gets the employer’s credit rating, which is presumably better than theirs, and the amount they trade is somehow subtracted from their wages. The practical way of doing it, taking into consideration PAYE etc, is that everyone gets paid their wages normally, then they buy credits to trade in mutual credit. That’s the most likely scenario. It’s absolutely doable. If we do it the way I’ve just described, there’s no legislation to worry about, because wages still happen in hard currency. Plus we think that employers will probably offer a discount as well – maybe sell £1.05 of credit for £1, because it will be good value for them.

Can you see a route to getting ‘new economy’ players – eg community energy groups, CSA groups, housing co-ops, worker co-ops, credit unions trading in mutual credit? How do we get there?

The same benefits of risk reduction and access to better credit applies to any trading entity, whether they call themselves a social enterprise or a co-op or a rapacious capitalist organisation – it makes just as much sense for anyone to join. What matters is reciprocal trading relationships. Western economies are very vertical – businesses buy from bigger businesses and sell to smaller businesses, and you end up with, for example, a corner shop selling to an individual. That’s been massively aggregated. Covid means that big businesses have become entire supply chains, selling direct to consumers – so the scope for intertrading is being reduced in the economy as a whole. This is why it’s so risky, and we keep having economic crashes – the economy is unstable, because it doesn’t have enough variety in it. So it’s difficult to find businesses that have a relatively high proportion of their trade as intertrade with other businesses. But we’ve got some (hot off the press) rigorous analytics to show that the benefits are real, and we’re going to be investigating what proportion of trade counts as intertrade, and looking into that more.

How does the clubs idea, as it grows, dovetail with what Matthew’s doing with the credit commons? I’ll interview Matthew next, to get his perspective.

What we’re doing is providing the layer on top of the technical specification of the credit commons that makes it easy for ordinary businesses to use and understand, and we’re working to continually make less about strange conversations about money and more about building something that’s just like what people are used to. Just look for a business that says they’re part of the mutual credit world, and you can pay them easily, like using paypal or a bank transfer.

I can see how an accountant or a local authority could convene a club. Who else might be able to?

Business network organisers of all kinds. There are lots of business networks all over the country, ranging from ‘you scratch my back and I’ll scratch yours’ networks to friendly Rotary Club types that meet in the pub, to solidarity networks in disadvantaged communities of one sort or another that know that they need to help each other, to campaigning business groups that want to promote a certain type of business. The Co-op is the biggest one of these. Any group of value-producing organisations that do a certain amount of trade together – doesn’t have to be a high proportion – that want to work more collaboratively, to get some benefit in relation to the wider world. Mutual assurance is the term for that.

What about an individual who might want to start a business network in their town?

That’s a great thing if someone can do it. It’s easier if you’re already well-connected. If you’re trying to do it by cold-calling businesses, that’s great, but it will be hard work. You might be better off finding a few other people to work with first. As time goes by, we’ll be producing more materials and toolkits, but we don’t have those yet. But we will.

Can it all be done without brokering? Sardex, who you mentioned earlier, have a lot of paid brokers – will these be needed for small networks of businesses that already trade with each other, and may not have hard cash post-Covid?

Sardex is interesting. It’s the model we used for the OCN. There’s one big network, rather than small groups that know each other. Even though it’s Sardinia, an island with a small population, there are 4000 businesses in the Sardex network, and it’s true that the only way they’ve been able to keep trading volumes up is by having brokers on the phone all the time, telling traders about opportunities / deals etc. That’s a brake on Sardex’s development, because it’s very expensive. What we’re hoping that if the structure that emerges is of relatively small groups that are already trade with each other, they won’t need brokers to get them to trade with each other, because they already do. They’ll see straightforward business benefits, like improvements in cashflow, reductions in risk. Then over time, with increases in access to interest-free credit, they’ll want to do more. When those networks aggregate together into networks of networks – so there might be a regional network with a lot of clubs of between 10 and 100 businesses – whether it’s then obvious that it’s beneficial to trade across that network, with businesses you don’t already know and trade with. Then, whether it will be possible to trade without any brokering at all, remains to be seen. The best idea we have is that we’ll have freelance brokers, so there might be a market for referrals.

So we’ll just have to wait and see.

Yes.

What successes have you had so far?

The biggest, obvious one is that working with a brilliant local food partnership called Food Plymouth, and some local food business consultants who’ve worked with the Open Food Network – another great organisation, we’ve put together a bid to Innovate UK (govt. money) with a proposition for building a model for local food business networks, and we got funding to start a project that will be finished next year, and that has mutual credit built in at the core, as a key plank of increasing the margins and the benefits of participation for all the small businesses that have to come together to form a local food network. Assessors from the government, who don’t care about new economy stuff, thought it was a good proposition.

We’re also working with some accountants – we’ve been talking to them philosophically, but we’ve been asked to build clubs for them. So they want to help design clubs that work well for accountants.

We’ve got a group of community businesses – dynamic, interesting people in Brixton, and Lambeth council are interested in a project too.

And we’re just starting a conversation with a fantastic group of businesses in London called the East End Trades Guild – 300 businesses, many traditional, local small businesses, plus some people with real vision about how to move the collaborative economy forward, and they’re interested in the idea of a credit club.

I’ve talked with people from Chelsea Green about having a mutual credit account. They said they’d talk with colleagues. I’d like to walk the walk and for people to be able to buy the book with mutual credit. Not sure how that would work though, with a big international publisher.

Very interesting. I’d have to think about it. It raises all sorts of interesting problems. If Chelsea Green take mutual credit in payment, they need to know they can spend them. They can pay some of your fees, but where are you going to spend it?

Well, my accountant takes mutual credit, and has taken it, via the OCN.

Hopefully your fee for the book will be larger than your accountant’s bill! But this illustrates the question that one always needs to ask about any participant in a mutual credit economy – you have to look at the other side of the equation. So for the people buying your book in mutual credit, you’d have to ask where they’re going to earn credits into balance. Those questions need some thought. There’s a long history of mutual credit start-ups that operated on the ‘build it and they will come’ mentality, who didn’t know how it was going to pan out, but if they made something beautiful, and enough people join, it’ll all sort itself out. The sad reality is that it doesn’t, because those questions really matter. People who earn a lot of credits think that’s great – but it’s only great if you can spend it. If they look around the network and can’t find anything they want, or anyone who actually accepts credits, they’ll quickly become dissatisfied. Or – if people get a big negative balance, and they’re not allowed to spend any more because they’ve reached their limit (and there might be an official system limit, that prevents trades beyond a limit), then they’re going to want to earn; and if they can’t find anyone who will pay them credits for whatever they’re willing to provide, then they’re going to be disaffected, and may walk away.

It’s worth anyone interested in experiencing this going to join Simbi.com. You can join for free – it’s a global mutual credit network, with a beautiful app, thousands of members, they give you free credits to start with. You can see what it’s like to be in a ‘build it and they will come’ network, because although everything about it is great, it just has this flabby, unreal feeling to it. We believe in not building networks for places and groups that we can’t predict will get some fairly immediate concrete payback from their commitment.

Finally, would a credit commons, a mutual credit economy, have to grow forever, like the current economy does. Could it stabilise so that we can live without destroying nature?

There’s really good precedent on this. There are a lot of LETS schemes, that operate on mutual credit principles and mechanisms. Lots of LETS schemes that started up as long ago as the 90s still survive, and those networks don’t want to grow. They’ve become networks of 20-25 people. They’re friends, and it’s quite hard to join those groups. They’ve stopped bothering either to keep accounts – they just do stuff for each other. The whole point of mutual credit is that it emphasises the value exchange (I want something – a book, some babysitting – anything) over the number of credits. There’s a theory of exchange that says if the amount of money in a system doesn’t change then no value was created – but that’s obviously nonsense, because why would 2 people go to the bother of making a trade if they didn’t both feel better after it? So there’s always value created in a trade, but not necessarily in numbers of units – it’s human value. So what we hope and assume that yes, mutual credit will not have an inbuilt growth imperative, like the money we use at the moment does – because people take money out of circulation, for savings, and because of the fact that the banks create money from interest-bearing debt, so people have to go and do work, before they can clear their account.

Thanks Dil. Any questions you have for Dil – please post them on the blog, or on YouTube – but they’ll have a better chance of being answered on the blog. Dil, I’ll blog your ‘2 Planks and a Bridge’ article soon. This is the first of a series of interviews accompanying the book, so if you want to follow them, subscribe to the blog and / or the YouTube channel.

Yes, if I said anything too fast, or in jargon, please ask and I’ll try to explain more fully.

9 Comments

  • Thanks Dave and Dil for an interesting series unfolding. I’ve some questions arising from a couple of things Dil said here – questions that I’ve already raised and which we might have to agree to differ on, but heregoes…

    On trust:

    You rightly state that a trading group is hard to create as such and so MCS prefers to work with pre-existing trading circles (where trading trust already exists) in order to create working models. That excludes most of us for now, alas! I agree that one probably has to be well placed/connected to create a mutual credit trading circle – unfortunately in this age of social atomisation, many of us are not well placed/connected (and that is exactly why we need mutual credit so sorely!).

    You didn’t quite say this above, and I’ve said it before, but I repeat: I don’t think the Open Credit Network error was the ‘build it and they will come’ error. As a would-be trader in the OCN, I never doubted that trade would work fine there: I trusted you, the convenors, and by extension trusted the trading members. There are three nested reasons why I didn’t start trading through the OCN, and none of these has to do with lack of trust: 1. For legal reasons as a sole-trader I had to sell before I could buy; 2. there was no ready showcase for the things I could buy as a consumer or for the things I wanted to sell as a producer; 3. there was no ready networking tool other than clunky emails effectively from cold. So those were the obstacles for me in starting to trade in that marketplace: legal issues, and an inadequate ‘shopping’ platform (sorry to use that word!).

    On Etsy or eBay on the other hand, I don’t need to know a business I trade with; I usually look at their feedback scores before making a purchase, but some consumers don’t even feel the need to do that. To a sufficient extent I can jduge the quality of their offer by the integrity of their listing (and even the poor quality listings usually come good).

    When eBay started out, there were naysayers who presumably were late adopters, but there were enough brave buyers willing to give it a go well before vendors had built up feedback scores (and vendors willing to trust unknown buyers, too). And this was in the early days of the internet, so early adopters were facing the additional and potentially very daunting obstacle of using classified ads *online* to agree to transactions *online* (and in good, honest spirit as eBay reached its second chapter of evolution, dutifully sending their transaction fees via snail mail to Pierre Omidyar).

    So I’m wondering, is trust more important in a mutual credit scheme than in any other kind of marketplace? Is it because we can’t expect people to trust in our currency (mutual credit units) as much as they currently trust in our government’s currency? And is this really true, do we trust in our government’s currency to an extent that we don’t (yet?) trust in mutual credit units? (Really?)

    I’ve asked you this before, and I end up concluding that you don’t mean trust but rather confidence, i.e. I have to have confidence that after earning mutual credit units I will be able to spend them again, i.e. I have to have confidence that your (unusual) marketplace will work.

    So that brings us back to questions of reciprocity, circularity and critical mass in the marketplace for a ‘thick’ market with liquidity. However, these do not have to be an obstacle.

    Your superpower, as well as federatability for diversity and critical mass, is the periodic cash clearing process: if, as a successful vendor in a mutual credit scheme, I haven’t spent the credits I’ve earnt in a given accounting period, then they will come back to me in cash from whichever buyers still owe the community pot by having bought more than they sold, no? That is, the balance sheet goes back to zero? Even if there are no other transactions in the marketplace besides the one in whcih I’ve been a vendor, there’s no problem: at the end of our agreed accounting period my buyer simply has to pay me in my national currency. So I don’t need to have either trust or confidence in this marketplace, because the worst that will happen is nothing; at best, I will either gain credits or cash to the value of anything I’ve sold. And if I’m the buyer, then I will either a) buy nothing; or b) pay for something in mutual credit units; or c) pay for something in cash. That is: no risk; no losers (apart from defaulting, disappearance or death, which affect any marketplace and the first two of which are ordinarily pursuable with ordinary legal instruments, as you say here Dil).

    Am I wrong? Does your ledger/software not work like this?

    2. Symbi: you describe it as ‘flabby’ – please can you say more about this? I’m not sure whether Symbi is a useful comparison given that it is 100% moneyless as far as I know, but it’d be really helpful to hear yous articulate the difference between a LETS scheme and your mutual credit scheme.

    Thanks as always guys.

    Eloïse

  • Dave Darby says:

    Hi Eloise.
    The problems you mention with the OCN were largely technological, and will apply to clubs too at first – and can be overcome in time. But for me there were deeper problems.
    1. When I was recruiting for the OCN, the most common objection was that businesses already had their trading relationships, and they were usually local. Trading in the OCN would have meant developing new trading relationships and dropping old ones.
    2. Looking at Sardex, a big (although not as big as the UK, obviously) network covering the whole of Sardinia – I think they have around 40 staff, mostly brokers, constantly chasing businesses to suggest and encourage trades. This would suggest to me that those trades don’t come naturally. Scaling up, we would have needed an army of brokers to keep trade going in a UK network.
    3. The idea is that local groups won’t need much in the way of staff or brokering. Member businesses could just see it as a way of giving each other trade credits until the end of the month (say), when netting off can happen to bring all accounts back to zero, or within pre-agreed limits. That could just be an immediate benefit to small businesses without having to think about new ways of trading or new business relationships. This overcomes the potential problems with sole traders too – groups of businesses offering each other 30-day trade credit is nothing new. Regulators might not have understood a national organisation allowing businesses that are new to each other, trading in mutual credit (even though the OCN wouldn’t have been offering credit – the businesses would be offering credit to each other).
    4. This may just be me, but I’m risk averse, and having a giant organisation at the heart of UK mutual credit doesn’t seem right to me. If it were to be closed down for some reason, or suffered some sort of cyber attack, that would be a massive setback, whereas federated local groups is a different thing altogether, with no centre to attack or close down.
    5. It’s about community building for me too, not building a giant Etsy-type organisation. The community-building aspect is as important as the non-monetary trade I think, plus shortening supply chains is good for environmental reasons.
    6. I always envisaged any kind of national grouping as a network of clubs, with maybe a few national businesses like the Phone Coop. Not even a network of clubs, but a network of networks of clubs – and so on, up to the global level.
    7. Reputation – I could see a scenario where businesses joined the OCN, bought from businesses they had no previous trading relationship with, then just disappeared and never traded again – not necessarily with evil intent. I think this is much less likely with trusted groups of businesses (local or otherwise – if they know each other, I think reputations would be damaged).
    8. I’m keen on the idea of building new local economies around a mutual credit core – community energy, CSA, social care co-ops, housing co-ops, sole traders, all kinds of co-ops, and then ‘replicating and federating’ to grow a new kind of economy from grassroots. I think there are plenty of exising business and social enterprise networks, plus accountants, onside local authorities, chambers of commerce, rotary club-type orgs etc. who would see the benefits and get the ball rolling, and once something is growing, others could see the benefits too, and start new networks – geographical or sectoral. It could help new small businesses start, if they have a network to join that will commit to buy from them if they reciprocate.

    Comparison with LETS is a whole new subject. I’ll get back on that one.

  • Dave Darby says:

    I’ll try to get Dil to elaborate on why small and federated might be better than large and centralised – but I think it is. ‘Replicate and Federate’. Big, centralised institutions never end well – even ones that start as co-ops. For me, it’s a combination of moving beyond human scale, dilution of democracy and leaving open the possibility of being seized / bought by a group that don’t share your values (e.g. the Co-op Bank).

    Good idea to have the conversation in public, btw.

  • Steve Gwynne says:

    Sorry I disappeared from last mutual credit blog. As I explained earlier I’m time/energy constrained.

    There isn’t any details about the £4bn levelling up fund so it might be a red herring.

    However I did find this which might be useful although Dil might have already seen it since he mentioned of Innovate UK
    https://www.gov.uk/topic/housing/funding-programmes

    Dil mentioned collaborative economy a few times which is presumably a core principle underlying mutual credit systems which fits very neatly with the latest iteration of the Equality/Inequality debate (equality of outcome vs equality of opportunity) with Sandel speaking of a third way, equality of worth/condition which he sees as an exercise in collaboration, especially in terms of mutual recognition and what Rawls termed “agree to share one another’s fate”.

    Therefore I can’t help but think that the mutual credit system is part of this wider debate about how to recalibrate our social relations towards ‘the interdependency principle’ away from the individualism of equality of opportunity and the collectivism of equality of outcome.

    At this stage I have nothing to add to that except that I think this debate is going to be a defining feature of our politics for the foreseeable future. So I thought I’d mention that in relation to book title/subtitle.

  • Dil Green says:

    Hi Eloise,

    Thanks for the thoughtful comments and questions. I’m going to respond to each separately.

    So I’m wondering, is trust more important in a mutual credit scheme than in any other kind of marketplace? Is it because we can’t expect people to trust in our currency (mutual credit units) as much as they currently trust in our government’s currency? And is this really true, do we trust in our government’s currency to an extent that we don’t (yet?) trust in mutual credit units? (Really?).

    I wrote a whole blog post last year called ‘Operationalised Trust‘ around this issue. I realised after I had written it that it needed some refinement in exactly the way you suggest – to make the distinction between trust between people, and confidence in the currency/means-of-exchange.

    The TL;DR goes like this:

    • Any currency is a promise in the the context of some social group that a currency unit will be accepted at a future date as payment for something of value (ref Thomas Greco, the writing on a UK banknote).
    • That the important difference between a ‘debt’ and a ‘promise’ is that the former is hard-edged, while promises are understood as likely to be broken sometimes (ref David Graeber, also ‘Promise theory’).
    • That what matters with a promise, is the degree of confidence we have in its being kept – and that this is the key requirement for a currency that can work as a means of exchange – the degree of confidence in the promise it makes being kept within the social setting where it operates.
    • That confidence can come from a number of attributes, of which the key ones are ‘Trust’, ‘Power’, and ‘Momentum’:
        • Trust between the members of the society – we believe that they will strive to honour the promise as a society
        • Power – the determination of that society to defend the confidence in its currency – ultimately by force.
        • Momentum – the degree to which the currency is enshrined in the culture of that society, the scale of that society.
    • That we can look at different types of money in terms of the mix of these three sources of confidence, and see what type of society is required to provide confidence in different types of currency.

    So if we look at fiat currencies, we can see that they derive most of their confidence from the power of the central authorities that issue them (both in might and in will-to-violence, even against their own citizens, to defend the currency’s value), that trust is very low – and falling. Momentum for these currencies is described by the Foreign Exchange Markets in terms of ‘hard’ and ‘soft’ – and only the ‘hard’ currencies – those which have momentum can ‘power through’ crises by printing more (QE). An interesting outcome of this is that crises in fiat money are usually due to shortages of willing buyers – essentially, people see the power exerted to defend the value in piles of hard currency as giving a better hedge against future uncertainty that the things they could buy with it.

    We can look at cryptocurrencies and see that they have responded to lack of trust between people, and a distrust of states by giving supposedly absolute power to a putatively incorruptible machine (neither of which extremes actually comes true). The novelty and incomprehensibility of crypto means that its momentum is low, and thus it is subject to wild speculator driven swings.

    If we look at Mutual Credit, we can see that power will be low (for the foreseeable future at least), that momentum will equally be low, and that thus trust between members is crucial if there is to be confidence in the viability of any project. The failure mode of mutual Credit schemes is not lack of willing buyers, but lack of willing sellers – people unwilling to accept Mutual Credit in payment because they lack confidence that its promise will be kept.

  • Dil Green says:

    Eloise, you said;

    Your superpower, as well as federatability for diversity and critical mass, is the periodic cash clearing process: if, as a successful vendor in a mutual credit scheme, I haven’t spent the credits I’ve earnt in a given accounting period, then they will come back to me in cash from whichever buyers still owe the community pot by having bought more than they sold, no?

    I want to be clear here about terms. When we at Mutual Credit Services describe a Trade Credit Club, we are talking about a particular set of arrangements that put together a number of ideas.

    The basis of the type of means of exchange currency we are talking about here is ‘Producer Credit’ – that it the the creators of value in an economy who should be the basis of credit creation – paying for items they buy in ‘credit units’ they create at the point of purchase, which are accepted on the basis of their future will to sell their produce in return for those units. This is EC Riegel’s term from the early part of the C20th.

    Onto that idea is layered ‘Mutual Credit’ – the contemporary understanding of which grew from Michael Linton’s introduction of LETS schemes in the late 1980s – where a number of economic actors come together and agree on a common credit unit which all will accept in payment.

    Onto that is layered the ‘Credit Commons’ – a protocol whereby Mutual Credit groups can be federated together without losing their integrity or sovereignty, proposed by Matthew Slater and Tim Jenkin.

    The final layer, which is required for the Trade Credit Clubs model, is to add in the idea of ‘third entry book-keeping’ which we derive from the work of Chris Cook, which allows all trade within a group to be ‘settled’ in an internal credit unit. Aggregation into a communal ledger allows all trade to be ‘netted off’ so that each member has a single balance in respect of the group as a whole. It is this balance which is brought back into line with agreed Mutual Credit account limits (not necessarily to zero) at each settlement period.

    The need for trust and confidence don’t, in my view, disappear with this model. Members need to trust other members to settle. And confidence is needed that any positive balance of internal Mutual Credit units will be ‘spendable’ – that a willing seller who will take Mutual Credit as payment will be found when needed.

  • Dil Green says:

    Eloise, you asked;

    Symbi: you describe it as ‘flabby’ – please can you say more about this? I’m not sure whether Symbi is a useful comparison given that it is 100% moneyless as far as I know, but it’d be really helpful to hear you articulate the difference between a LETS scheme and your mutual credit scheme.

    LETS and Mutual Credit are essentially the same thing in terms of mechanics – so are Timebanks for that matter. The difference really comes from the way that groups are set-up, and in what context.

    In all of these, an accounting unit is agreed to be acceptable as a payment currency – a means-of-exchange within some bounded group. The sum of all balances is always zero across the group as a whole.

    Timebanks use hours as the unit, ideologically valuing every person’s time as equal.

    LETS schemes are typically person-to-person (p2p).

    Both of these approaches tend to come from the perspective of encouraging more value creating interactions in some community setting – by making it easier for relative strangers to discover matching wants and offers, and by accounting for that value creation.

    Since the goods and services exchanged within these groups are typically informal, ‘part-time’ and ‘leisure time’ based, they tend not to find it easy to interact effectively with the hard currency economy – people are happy to buy from businesses with mutual credit, but have little to sell to businesses.

    Mutual Credit in a business-to business (p2p) framing has the same mechanics, but has a different value-in-use. Since most businesses already give free credit to each other (30 days to pay), the immediate value is in risk-reduction and cashflow management – since to be paid immediately in a credit unit which is accepted by other businesses greatly reduces the fallout of default and eliminates late payment.

    As for Simbi, I think it is very much worthwhile for anyone interested in mutual credit to join up (it’s free and easy) and see if they can make some trades. It’s a global p2p mutual credit, very nicely implemented in technical terms, but all my attempts to trade there have lacked any real sense of urgency or interest – both buying and selling; its as if no-one there really believes in it. But that’s my impression – I do urge people to try it for themselves – there are lots of users and all sorts of services on offer/wanted.

  • Dave and Dil,

    Thank you for those thoughtful (as ever) and detailed responses. I will come back and read them again, but at first read our differences in outlook are confirmed again, but I’m also keen to emphasise that we’re not completely polarised! I seem to be more trusting and optimistic than yous, which affects some of the implementation decisions quite profoundly, but I feel pretty confident in and committed to my stance there 🙂

    I should clarify that I’m not envisaging anything giant (I am a craftsperson in a very niche network with some clear ideals to be exacted from co-traders, both professional and amateur), and that I too am wary of centralisation. I’m aware of shut-down risks but also observe that when (or if, in our case) a thing grows to the size of being a threat then it may well be too late to shut it down; or at least the idea would have gained enough traction to re-emerge in some other form or place.

    With the help of one or two key others in my working group I’m developing a model which dovetails p2b2p (etc.) exchange, and I’m excited about it. We won’t now have a proposal ready before Christmas but hope to have something to share in the new year.

    Cheers guys.

    Eloïse

Leave a Reply

Your email address will not be published. Required fields are marked *

This site uses Akismet to reduce spam. Learn how your comment data is processed.